The Regulatory Dilemma Created by Emerging Revenue Streams of Independent Telephone
Companies
Before the
National Association of Regulatory Utility
Commissioners 101st Annual Convention and Regulatory
Symposium
by
Michael J. Majoros, Jr.Snavely, King & Associates
I would like to thank the
National Association of Regulatory Utility’s Commissioners for inviting me
here today. The subject of today’s discussion is the “Emerging Revenue
Streams of Independent Telephone Companies” I would like to discuss the
dilemma that I believe these emerging revenue streams create for regulators.
Simply stated, the dilemma is that these streams for revenues can result in
what appears to be a good economic decision from the companies’ standpoint,
but a poor economic decision from the current ratepayers’ standpoint.
Recently, regulators have been faced
with requests to increase telephone company depreciation expense as a result
of accelerated plans for retirement of switch, circuitry, and copper cable.
Under rate base, rate of return regulation, the higher depreciation expense
may require an increase in rates to ratepayers or alternatively, may offset
rate reductions which otherwise might be warranted.
The accelerated retirement plans,
particularly those for switch replacements, are usually supported by
discounted cash flow studies. These studies compare the incremental cash flow
of alternative investment decisions. Since the consequence of these
replacement plans may be higher depreciation expense today, regulators are
obliged to consider the reasonableness of the plans. This necessarily
requires an evaluation of the underlying cash flow studies.
A typical example is a telephone
company’s decision to replace an existing electromechanical or electric analog
switch with a digital switch. Usually, the underlying cash flow studies
support the replacement decision. Of course, these studies, like all economic
studies, are based upon several assumptions that are subject to challenge and
change. Alternative assumptions may alter the results and change the overall
conclusion. With one exception, however, my discussion does not address
underlying assumptions. The dilemma I will address occurs even if all input
assumptions are 100 percent correct.
Studies
The three primary cash flow streams in telephone company analysis
are: (a) first cost, (b) incremental expenses, and (c) incremental revenues.
First cost is essentially the incremental
capital investment of each of the alternatives being studies relative to the
“base case,” usually the status quo. Incremental expenses are the change in
expense associated with each of the alternatives. Incremental revenues are the
additional revenues anticipated under each alternative. The incremental
revenues are the “emerging revenues streams” that are the subject of today’s
revenue streams as the anticipated additional future revenues that can only
provided by a digital switch. In other words, the emerging revenue streams
cannot be provided by existing electromechanical or electronic analog
switches.
In order to measure the net costs in
terms of present dollars, the net cash flow streams under each of the
alternatives are discounted at an interest rate reflective of the telephone
companies’ anticipated cost of capital. The alternative which provides the
highest positive net present value is determined to be the economic choice.
If the difference between the net
present value of the digital replacement and the base case is a positive
number, the replacement will be deemed to be economically justified. As I
indicated earlier, I have defined the emerging revenue streams as the
anticipated additional future revenues which can only be provided by a digital
switch. Therefore, the future revenue streams almost always favor digital
replacement since only the digital switch provide the emerging revenue
streams. Offsetting the revenue streams is the first cost of the digital
switch, which is like to be greater than any investment associated with
retaining the existing switch, particularly, if it is replacing an
electromechanical switch. Typically, the deciding factor is the impact of the
emerging digital revenue streams.
I have three handouts today.
Table 1 is a “Simulated Cash Flow Analysis Relating to a Complete Digital
Replacement of Existing Switch Investment.” This table is based upon an
actual cash flow analysis prepare by an independent telephone company. That
study addressed the complete replacement of the company’s several existing
non-digital and first generation digital switches. Table 1 was drawn from the
results of that study. I have changed the numbers in order to avoid
disclosure of the particular company involved. However, the numbers in my
table bear the same percentage relationships to each other as the actual
figures in the telephone company’s cash flow study. The figures in Column B
reflect discounted net present values of cash flow streams. Line 1 shows the
higher capital costs associated with the digital switches. The second line
shows the expense saving associated with digital switches. The third line
reflects the net salvage value of the retired switches, and the fourth line
shows the additional income taxes associated with higher revenues, expenses
and investment. The fifth line shows the emerging digital revenue streams.
As one can see, it is a positive value. Line six (which is the sum of line 1
to 5) is the net present value of the entire digital replacement plan. This
is a positive value. Therefore, the Company would conclude that the
replacement of all existing non-digital and first generation digital switches
is economically justified on the basis of the $1,000 positive value of the
discounted cash flow streams.
The question posed by this exhibit
is “What impact do the emerging revenue streams have on the economical
justification for the digital replacement program.” To answer, I would like
to refer you to
Table 2. Table 2 demonstrates the impact for the emerging revenue streams
on the study results from Table 1. As you can see, the first line shows the
$1,000 economic justification for the digital replacement plan from Table 1.
On line 2, I have subtracted the emerging revenue streams, net of their
associated income taxes, from the economic justification. Line 3 demonstrated
that without the emerging revenue streams, the positive $1,000 economic
justification turns into a negative $842 economic penalty. The obvious
conclusion is that the emerging revenue streams overwhelmingly control the
results of this study. If it were not for these revenue streams, the
replacement plan would not be economically justified. Consequently, the
emerging revenue streams drove the replacement decision.
Accepting the company’s study as
performed, the regulator may conclude that the company’s decision to replace
the existing switches is economically justified, based primarily upon the
anticipation of future revenues. If the forecast of those revenues appears to
be reasonable then the regulatory would probably not object to the telephone
company’s replacement plan.
The regulators role, however, is not
to support the company’s profit maximization, but to represent the company’s
ratepayers. For their standpoint, the replacement has a very different
perspective. What is a good economic decision for the company is not
necessarily a good economic decision for the company’s current ratepayers.
One of the consequences of the cash
flow study underlying my Tables 1 and 2 was a request by the telephone company
for higher depreciation expense relating to the existing switches. The basis
of the request was that these switches have not and will not be fully
depreciated, using the existing depreciation rates, by the time the
replacements are made. Therefore, the telephone company requested that the
depreciation expense be increased to a level which would fully depreciate each
switch by its anticipated retirement date. If approved, this could result in
one of two situations. In situation 1, the telephone company may need to
increase its rate for service to cover the higher depreciation expense. In
situation 2, the telephone company may be able to absorb the increase expense
without increasing its rates for service because its earning are sufficiently
high. In other words, without the increased expense a rate reduction may have
been warranted. In either case, ratepayers would pay the higher depreciation
expense associated with the retirement of existing switches through rates for
monopoly services.
Table 3 is titles “Amortization of Existing Investment Resulting from
Digital Replacement Plan.” This table provides a simulation of the
incremental revenue requirements associated with the higher depreciation
expense relating to the existing switches. In other words, this table
provides the current ratepayers’s viewpoint of the replacement plan. Line 1
shows the original cost of existing switches. Line 2 shows the accumulated
depreciation and Line 3 shows their net book value of $5,000. Line 4 shows
the current depreciation expense at a 7 percent depreciation rate. Line 5
shows the additional depreciation expense if the existing investment is
amortized in one year. Line 6 shows an adjustment for estimated rate base
impacts and finally, line 7 shows the incremental revenue requirements
associated with one year amortization of the existing switches.
This revenue requirement effect may
be exaggerated because it assumes a one year amortization of the existing
switches. However, it is not unreasonable. I have observed cash flow studies
relating to individual switches which in fact, result in requests for one year
amortization of the switches anticipated to be replaced. The primary purpose
of Table 3 is to demonstrate the significant impact upon current ratepayers
resulting from the early retirement of existing switches. In this case, it
happened to be $3,654.
I have reviewed several telephone
company’s cash flow studies relating to the replacement of investments. I can
tell you that the ratepayer impact, that is, higher depreciation charges for
the retiring switch is never included in these studies. It is not include
because the investment dollars to which the higher depreciation expense
relates are deemed to be “sunk” that is, they are already spent and not
recoverable. In an unregulated environment, this would be a valid assumption
because once a dollar is spent, it is spent – it cannot be recovered in any
future cash flow. In a regulated environment, however, sunk capital costs can
in fact produce future cash flows. This is demonstrated in Table No 3. The
incremental revenue requirement in Table 3 pure cash flow to the utility
either in the form of higher rates or as foregone rate reductions.
This then, is the dilemma faced by
regulators. On the one hand, the company has economically justified its
decision to replace the switch, but on the other hand, that decision is flatly
uneconomic from the standpoint of current ratepayers. A good economic choice
from Company’s standpoint and a poor economic choice from the ratepayer’s
standpoint resulting from the same decision are not mutually exclusive.
Recognizing this possibility, regulators are faced with the dilemma of how to
make the decision economical for both the Company and its ratepayers.
There are probably several ways to
accomplish this goal, but it would seem to be that the fairest and the most
economically justified approach for all parties would be to match the higher
deprecation cost associated with the early retirement of the existing
investment with emerging revenue streams that caused the replacement decision
in the first place. Obviously, such a matching may require deferrals of cost
recognition until the creation of the revenue streams. These deferrals may
not necessarily adhere to a strict definition of depreciation expense as
spelled-out in the Uniform System of Accounts. Nevertheless, if properly
implemented such deferred cost recognition would be consistent with the
ratemaking concepts of matching, intergenerational equity, cost causation and
incremental costing. Using these principles, regulators have the tools to
eliminate the dilemma with which they are faced.
I would like to take this
opportunity to thank NARUC for inviting here today and thank all of you for
listening.
Biographical Sketch
Of
Michael J. Majoros, Jr.
Mr. Majoros is Vice President and
Treasurer of the economic consulting firm Snavely King & Associates, Inc.,
with offices at 1111 14th St. NW, Washington, DC 20005. He has been with
the firm since 1981. He provides consultation on accounting, financial,
management and regulatory issues and has testified as an expert witness in
more than forty regulatory proceedings involving telephone, electric, gas,
water, sewage, and waste removal companies. His testimony has addressed
issues such as taxation, divestiture accounting, revenue requirements, rate
base nuclear decommissioning, depreciation and capital recovery. Mr. Majoros
has been responsible for developing his firm’s consulting services on
depreciation and capital recovery matters. Prior to his current position, he
directed various management and regulatory consulting projects in the public
utility field for Van Scoyoc & Wiskup. Other previous positions included
Treasurer of a heavy equipment sales firm and Auditor for Ernst & Ernst. Mr.
Majoros holds a B.S. in Accounting from the University of Baltimore. Mr.
Majoros has passed the CPA exam and is a member of the American Institute of
Certified Public Accountants, Maryland Association of C.P.A.’s, and the
Society of Depreciation Professionals. Among Mr. Majoros’ publications are:
“Telephone Company Deferred Taxes and Investment Tax Credits – A Capital Loss
for Ratepayers,” Public Utility Fortnightly, September 27, 184. “The Use of
Customer Discount Rates in Revenue Requirement Comparison,” Proceedings of the
25th Annual Iowa State Regulatory Conference, 1986.
Table 1
Snavely, King & Associates, Inc.
Simulated Cash Flow Analysis Complete Digital Replacement Of Existing Switch Investment |
|
|
Study Results (Company’s Viewpoint) |
|
|
|
|
|
Description
(a) |
|
Discounted Net Present Value
(b) |
|
|
|
1. Higher Capital Cost of Digital Switches |
|
($1,752) |
2. Expense Saving Associated with Digital
Switches |
|
998 |
3. Net Salvage Value of Retired Switches |
|
162 |
4. Additional Taxes |
|
(377) |
5. Emerging Digital Revenue Streams |
|
1,969 |
6. Net Present Value
of Digital Replacement Plan |
|
$1,000 |
|
|
|
CONCLUSION: The
replacement of all existing switches with digital switches justified on the basis of the $1,000
positive present value of the discounted flow streams.
Table 2
Snavely, King & Associates, Inc.
Simulated Cash Flow Analysis Complete Digital Replacement Of Existing Switch Investment |
|
|
Impact of Emerging Digital Revenue Streams (Company’s Viewpoint) |
|
|
|
|
|
Description
(a) |
|
Discounted Net Present
Value
(b) |
|
|
|
1. Economic Justification for Digital
Replacement Plan |
|
$1,000 |
2. Less: Impact of Emerging Digital Revenue
Streams |
|
|
a.
Revenue |
|
(1,969) |
b.
Taxes |
|
127 |
c. Net |
|
(1,842) (1,842) |
3. Adjusted Economic
Justification |
|
($842) |
|
|
|
CONCLUSION: The emerging digital
revenue streams overwhelmingly control the results of the study. If I were
not for these emerging revenue streams, the replacement plant would not be
economically justifies. Therefore, the revenue streams drove the replacement
decision.
Table 3
Snavely, King & Associates, Inc.
Amortization of Existing Investment Resulting From Digital Replacement Plan |
|
|
Revenue Requirement (Ratepayer’s Viewpoint) |
|
|
|
|
|
Description
(a) |
|
Discounted Net Present Value
(b) |
|
|
|
1. Original Cost of Existing Switches |
|
$15,000 |
2. Accumulated Depreciation |
|
(10,000) |
3. Net Book Value of Existing Switches |
|
5,000 |
4. Current Depreciation Expense At 7% (L1 x
.07) |
|
1,050 |
5. Additional
Depreciation Expense If Existing Investment Is Amortized In One Year (L3 - L4) |
|
3,950 |
6. Less Ratebase Impacts At a 15% Before Tax
Rate of Return |
|
(296) |
7. Incremental Revenue
Requirement |
|
$3,654 |
[1]
From Table 1
|